Disposable Jobs
Debunking Economics - the podcastSeptember 04, 2024x
373
37:0251 MB

Disposable Jobs

A couple of years ago, when warning of the need to fight inflation, Jerome Powell, Governor of the US Federal Reserve says interest rate would rise and jobs might disappear. Yet, interest rates have risen, and unemployment hasn’t fallen anywhere near as much as expected. So, what’s going on? Does it mean, thankfully, that monetary policy isn’t working as well as expected? Now the talk is of a soft landing, where jobs have been protected and inflation has come down. The work of fine tuning by the central bank, or just a coincidence. Phil Dobbie and Steve Keen talk about the interplay between jobs, wages, inflation and central bank policy.

Hosted on Acast. See acast.com/privacy for more information.

[00:00:00] [SPEAKER_01]: Our overarching focus is using our tools to bring inflation back down to our 2% goal.

[00:00:05] [SPEAKER_01]: Reducing inflation is likely to require a sustained period of blow-trend growth, and it will very likely

[00:00:10] [SPEAKER_01]: be some softening of labor market conditions.

[00:00:12] [SPEAKER_00]: This is the debunking economics podcast with Steve Keen and Phil Dobbie.

[00:00:20] [SPEAKER_02]: Well, I was German powerly governor of the US Federal Reserve saying that they're going to put up

[00:00:24] [SPEAKER_02]: interest rates. This is a couple of years ago, more and more to care of inflation,

[00:00:28] [SPEAKER_02]: and jobs will go as a result he was admitting to that. But is that really?

[00:00:32] [SPEAKER_02]: Had a control inflation, now inflation is supposedly beaten in the US?

[00:00:36] [SPEAKER_02]: How quickly will those jobs come back? Or as the Fed seems to fear, will jobs continue to

[00:00:40] [SPEAKER_02]: disappear faster? And that might mean sharper rate cuts in the short term, trying to win

[00:00:45] [SPEAKER_02]: the back. Bit of a blunt instrument, isn't it? That's this week on the debunking economics podcast.

[00:00:56] [SPEAKER_02]: Now, in January this year, the unemployment rate in the United States was 3.7%

[00:01:01] [SPEAKER_02]: now it's up to 4.3% and the Federal Reserve is saying that they're keeping a close eye on

[00:01:06] [SPEAKER_02]: the labor market in case that unemployment rate worsens due to their action, of course.

[00:01:12] [SPEAKER_02]: So, Steve, it is their fault. One of the powers they have as a central bank

[00:01:16] [SPEAKER_02]: used to make people unemployed, and we had during power confessing to that. So, dropping

[00:01:21] [SPEAKER_02]: interest rates to stop people losing their jobs is presumably one central bank action.

[00:01:25] [SPEAKER_02]: You would approve of, well, we're going to try and fix the problem that we've created.

[00:01:30] [SPEAKER_03]: Yeah, I mean the question with any of their tools work the way they think they do.

[00:01:35] [SPEAKER_03]: When the answer is pretty much, when you look at the financial flows involved and so on categorically

[00:01:40] [SPEAKER_03]: no, it doesn't. But the one way they can slow down inflation is by crushing the economy,

[00:01:46] [SPEAKER_03]: which if I buckled it back in the United States, and that was going from interest rates,

[00:01:51] [SPEAKER_03]: which were all the order of 3 and 4 and 5% to 17, we've gone from 0 to 5.

[00:01:57] [SPEAKER_03]: And even though the numerical difference is a smaller, the impact of that change is bigger.

[00:02:06] [SPEAKER_03]: Both in terms of what the interest rate cash flow does to boost the economy.

[00:02:10] [SPEAKER_03]: But also what the high interest rates do to cripple people who are normally taking out credit

[00:02:14] [SPEAKER_02]: for things like housing loans. Yeah, and the problem is those people who came become unemployed,

[00:02:18] [SPEAKER_02]: weren't the people who were creating the inflation in the first place? That's part of the problem,

[00:02:22] [SPEAKER_02]: isn't it? That's part of the effectiveness of the whole thing.

[00:02:24] [SPEAKER_02]: But it comes. We wouldn't need to red-hine up to make a Jeff Bezos down unemployed.

[00:02:29] [SPEAKER_02]: That would be better if you'd be fun. That's right. Well, that is 100% interest rate, isn't it?

[00:02:34] [SPEAKER_02]: But the or more perhaps. But the, it does tend to steam roll as well,

[00:02:38] [SPEAKER_02]: doesn't it? So you talked, you know, talked about back in the 80s and we didn't quite get down to 0%,

[00:02:42] [SPEAKER_02]: did we with an inflame? It was not quite up to 5%. But if we go back to 2018, the US had 4.3%

[00:02:49] [SPEAKER_02]: unemployment early in the year by December that was 6.6% a year later.

[00:02:54] [SPEAKER_02]: It was nudging 10%. So we don't have to go back too far to see how bad things can get.

[00:03:02] [SPEAKER_02]: But it's always quick-sur-rise and then slow to fall. Just look at a graph. It's very easy to see.

[00:03:07] [SPEAKER_02]: Very quick to rise, slow to fall. So the good, so if it is, you know, a tactic being used by the Fed,

[00:03:14] [SPEAKER_02]: then the effect of it almost drags on to the next time they've got to use it.

[00:03:20] [SPEAKER_02]: So by that measure, it's not a good way of doing it. Is it?

[00:03:24] [SPEAKER_03]: No, and this is what the non-orthodox economists think opposed canes in the been arguing for

[00:03:27] [SPEAKER_03]: however long time. Physical policy is far faster to go back and far more effective.

[00:03:32] [SPEAKER_03]: So if you want to boost the economy, you increase the scale of the budget deficit.

[00:03:36] [SPEAKER_03]: If you want to reduce it, you reduce the level of the government deficit and what you're doing.

[00:03:40] [SPEAKER_03]: And this is what mainstream economists will never understand. They simply don't want to

[00:03:44] [SPEAKER_03]: understand it because they do. They've got to throw their entire paradigm out. The government

[00:03:48] [SPEAKER_03]: fiscal operations directly changed the amount of money in the economy. Whereas the interest rate

[00:03:54] [SPEAKER_03]: at best shows that the price of money, but part of the way they do it actually boosts

[00:03:59] [SPEAKER_03]: aggregate demand, which is appointed more in Moses being making for a while, but only in the financial

[00:04:04] [SPEAKER_03]: sector. So it's much more complicated than their models make out and they're long and variable

[00:04:12] [SPEAKER_03]: lags or he's been talking about. I mean as you say, how long it takes the economy to recover from

[00:04:16] [SPEAKER_02]: this stupid operation? So how do you keep people employed and solve the problem with inflation

[00:04:23] [SPEAKER_02]: and do that in two fiscal measures? Because the issue is of course, there's money swimming

[00:04:28] [SPEAKER_02]: around people who have got money to spend but there's not the supply to meet that. So that's

[00:04:33] [SPEAKER_02]: you know, forces prices up. How do you how do you create that with fiscal measures? Well I'm in

[00:04:37] [SPEAKER_03]: for a start. You look at actually what the price on them is. And again they're different

[00:04:40] [SPEAKER_03]: of what the textbook's teach. So the textbooks tell you that if you want to increase the level of

[00:04:44] [SPEAKER_03]: output, you've got to hire more workers to do it. And because you hire them more workers but

[00:04:49] [SPEAKER_03]: you've got the same amount of machinery, the amount per worker falls as you add more workers

[00:04:54] [SPEAKER_03]: and therefore the cost of production rises. That is carigot categorically wrong about real

[00:04:59] [SPEAKER_03]: corporations. Real companies have excess capacity which they know they need to be able to

[00:05:06] [SPEAKER_03]: take on if demand grows faster than their initial plans, which is good news of course,

[00:05:10] [SPEAKER_03]: than they can expand without needing to install new machines. If they're competitive

[00:05:14] [SPEAKER_03]: stuff's up, they can move into the bracket and they never get to the stage where they have

[00:05:20] [SPEAKER_03]: the two workers one jackhammer which is the sort of nonsense that comes out of textbooks when you

[00:05:26] [SPEAKER_03]: actually put it into a physical example. So when this is actually examined by two of the leading

[00:05:30] [SPEAKER_03]: conventional conservative economists who are going to guys kiddling in press card,

[00:05:35] [SPEAKER_03]: if you pretty hard to find more of more reactionary pair of mainstream economists than that

[00:05:38] [SPEAKER_03]: duo. But they did a very nice statistical study of the economy,

[00:05:43] [SPEAKER_03]: way back in the 90s which had the title, I think monetary facts and a monetary myth or some

[00:05:50] [SPEAKER_03]: title like that, and they concluded that growing economy causes a smaller rate of inflation not

[00:05:57] [SPEAKER_03]: a higher one. So we've got textbooks which pump out stuff that looks scientific when you

[00:06:08] [SPEAKER_03]: and that's what people in central banks are unfortunately, often out without even realizing

[00:06:13] [SPEAKER_03]: because they don't read the literature as widely as I do. They're using concepts which categorically

[00:06:19] [SPEAKER_03]: you're in the opposite direction to what they think they're doing. Yeah well of course you can

[00:06:22] [SPEAKER_02]: take the wrong argument put numbers behind it and call it science, can't you? And I think that

[00:06:26] [SPEAKER_02]: that happens a bit. Because I mean the counter argument, I mean if they're saying well okay there's

[00:06:31] [SPEAKER_02]: too much money therefore people need to lose their job so that they've got less money to spend

[00:06:34] [SPEAKER_02]: so there's less demand. I mean that's fine but that's only one side of the coin isn't it? The

[00:06:38] [SPEAKER_02]: other side of the coin is those people are not producing anything anymore so actually the productive

[00:06:42] [SPEAKER_02]: capacity of the country is declined therefore the ability for you to you know so the supply demand

[00:06:48] [SPEAKER_02]: imbalance, uh, give worsens further. Far better surely which I think is what you're saying give more

[00:06:54] [SPEAKER_02]: people jobs increase productive capacity then that supply demand can straight disappear because

[00:07:00] [SPEAKER_03]: you've also, I mean the other thing about the ups and downs of the economy is that

[00:07:05] [SPEAKER_03]: this is often driven by you know what capitalists do which sometimes successful sometimes fail

[00:07:10] [SPEAKER_03]: the BIMS and the BAS and particularly when you're talking about the financial speculation

[00:07:14] [SPEAKER_03]: like we saw at the 2007 financial crash which you know if you're going to be if you want to find

[00:07:19] [SPEAKER_03]: guilty parties they're all working for banks. They're not the people who took out ninja loans

[00:07:23] [SPEAKER_03]: that the people who offered them in the first place. Yeah but what ends up being the impact of

[00:07:28] [SPEAKER_03]: the failure that ends up falling on the people who take out the ninja loans who are

[00:07:32] [SPEAKER_03]: conned by bankers. So one of the arguments that modern monetary theory makes that I'm generally

[00:07:36] [SPEAKER_03]: supportive of, I've got some criticisms is the idea of a job guarantee and that is that rather

[00:07:41] [SPEAKER_03]: if you lose your job if you become an unemployed because of the BIMS and BAS of the business cycle

[00:07:45] [SPEAKER_03]: and the ups and downs of financial speculation then there's a you rather than being unemployed

[00:07:52] [SPEAKER_03]: and therefore going through all the negatives that go with that you get a job guarantee which

[00:07:57] [SPEAKER_03]: is a you know lower pay than your full-time job was but it's work and it's money coming in

[00:08:03] [SPEAKER_03]: and then that then means that you you're you're a buffet you've still got an encouragement

[00:08:08] [SPEAKER_03]: to go back and find a job at some point but you not put into the debilitating situation

[00:08:13] [SPEAKER_03]: of being unemployed and sitting on your ass watching your bills mount up and wondering whether

[00:08:17] [SPEAKER_03]: you can survive and that's the reality I know anybody who's been through about an employment

[00:08:22] [SPEAKER_03]: and I've been through two in my life. You know that feeling and it's not one that is actually

[00:08:29] [SPEAKER_03]: create positive positive behavior on the other side it's an awful experience

[00:08:34] [SPEAKER_03]: that a lot of people get forced into. Yeah we've always done the other way. Yeah we've always

[00:08:39] [SPEAKER_02]: yeah we've even worse as perhaps being a job which pays such a low pay that you kind of

[00:08:42] [SPEAKER_02]: afford to pay your bills and you haven't got the time to get another job because you're too busy

[00:08:45] [SPEAKER_02]: doing the job that's not paying you enough so you know we all be through back so that in our

[00:08:49] [SPEAKER_02]: life which is perhaps you know looking back on it is perhaps quite healthy because it gives you

[00:08:53] [SPEAKER_02]: that drive but at the time it's not particularly good but unemployment in the US and around

[00:08:58] [SPEAKER_02]: the world really I mean it's historically low despite these high interest rates so 3.4% in the

[00:09:03] [SPEAKER_02]: US in April last year that was the lowest since December 1969. Do you believe that?

[00:09:09] [SPEAKER_03]: Yeah I do but again again being old enough to remember the 60s I was actually there and

[00:09:14] [SPEAKER_03]: two young to get stoned an unemployment rate of in Australia was really excited to

[00:09:22] [SPEAKER_03]: send the average was about one and a half he had a couple of bouts when it reached almost 4%

[00:09:27] [SPEAKER_03]: but there was a really serious severe dividing line between the good times and the bad times

[00:09:35] [SPEAKER_03]: the good times were back and when we had what are called called Cains Union policies with dominant

[00:09:41] [SPEAKER_03]: and then in 1974 you had a jump in both inflation and the rate of unemployment which could

[00:09:47] [SPEAKER_03]: come down to stag flation and that led to Milton Friedman becoming dominant in economic policy globally

[00:09:53] [SPEAKER_03]: and driving out the idea that you can manage the economy using fiscal policy you have to switch

[00:09:59] [SPEAKER_03]: over to central banks being dominant and setting the interest rates and thinking that

[00:10:03] [SPEAKER_03]: controllability economy that way and the outcome has been that since that period when you look

[00:10:08] [SPEAKER_03]: at the thing that they're actually trying to achieve using those policies which was a high rate of

[00:10:17] [SPEAKER_03]: under the so-called bad Cains Union period was in America was of the order of about 4% real growth

[00:10:23] [SPEAKER_03]: per annum the growth since the new classicles took over has been about 2% per annum and we had

[00:10:30] [SPEAKER_03]: you know 50 years of it so it certainly accumulated it's impact over time and so it's

[00:10:37] [SPEAKER_03]: the arguments that you know we've got to use monetary policy due to this we can't use fiscal policy

[00:10:41] [SPEAKER_02]: the track record says Gargier what does he work because you know this time we've got these

[00:10:48] [SPEAKER_02]: very high interest rates and yet unemployment is as I say still historically low I mean much of

[00:10:54] [SPEAKER_02]: the fed approach with interest rates is dependent on slowing the economy through unemployment

[00:10:59] [SPEAKER_02]: but it's just not happening very tight policy people still working well until now I mean

[00:11:04] [SPEAKER_02]: now they're worried about it's all down to lags and in which case you know if it's down

[00:11:10] [SPEAKER_02]: lags we've got inflation beat and now we're going to pay the price for it after the event

[00:11:16] [SPEAKER_03]: yeah I mean again this is well there are a whole point about lags with fiscal policy versus lags

[00:11:21] [SPEAKER_03]: with monetary policy there isn't a normal there was almost no lag with fiscal policy

[00:11:26] [SPEAKER_03]: but the government decides to create more money by increasing its the gap between it spending

[00:11:32] [SPEAKER_03]: in taxation that money is thin as it's spent is in the economy and it is spent the government

[00:11:37] [SPEAKER_03]: first when you know bill by goods and services off the of the private sector or it will give

[00:11:42] [SPEAKER_03]: somebody who's unemployed or on welfare a payment and that money has then probably normally

[00:11:48] [SPEAKER_03]: spent very rapidly so the lags are very brief in the case of of monetary policy there are

[00:11:55] [SPEAKER_03]: it's best most that there's the straightforward lag in terms of the impact of the government

[00:12:00] [SPEAKER_03]: putting up its rates versus the private sector following with high rates which by the way is

[00:12:04] [SPEAKER_03]: necessary for come back to that but that's what normally happens but then it's also how long

[00:12:10] [SPEAKER_03]: it takes that private increase in interest rates to actually affect economic demand and in

[00:12:15] [SPEAKER_03]: America because virtually all mortgages are fixed term like you take out a million 30 years

[00:12:22] [SPEAKER_03]: it's only the it's only the new borrowers who don't turn up because of high interest rates so

[00:12:28] [SPEAKER_03]: it's only an impact on what the economists love to call the marginal by the marginal by a

[00:12:33] [SPEAKER_03]: but it encourages like the stroller and the UK we have more floating interest rates than

[00:12:39] [SPEAKER_03]: the effect is more immediate but it's still lag is still takes time for the banks to

[00:12:43] [SPEAKER_03]: decide to put up the rates you know let you know you're going to pay a higher amount etc etc

[00:12:47] [SPEAKER_03]: so the timing effect with the monetary policy and the monetary effect of monetary policy is

[00:12:54] [SPEAKER_03]: well quite different to what the economic models say there and yeah and the at the fiscal approach

[00:12:59] [SPEAKER_02]: I mean just think Australia in 2007 2008 must have been 2008 Kevin rather than newly

[00:13:04] [SPEAKER_02]: the new Prime Minister Kevin Kevin 07 one of the first things he did was the the start of

[00:13:10] [SPEAKER_02]: the crisis in 2008 was to say well I can't go to put a thousand dollars or whatever it was

[00:13:15] [SPEAKER_02]: into everyone's bank accounts and everyone went off shopping sadly they bought flat screen TVs

[00:13:20] [SPEAKER_02]: which were sort of like in demand at the time which sort of meant that Australia's import shot out

[00:13:24] [SPEAKER_02]: but you know at least it helped Harvey Norman the retail store and that's the thing I mean

[00:13:29] [SPEAKER_03]: the money was instantaneously and your pocket and spent immediately and the country

[00:13:35] [SPEAKER_03]: the country but the retail industry do you know which and that's one of my pet pleas

[00:13:40] [SPEAKER_03]: of course because I was sort of castigated for the fact that I said there was going to be a

[00:13:44] [SPEAKER_03]: recession Australia and it didn't happen therefore I had to be wrong in fact what really happened

[00:13:49] [SPEAKER_03]: was and actually I've got said this interesting work that the macro business did recently

[00:13:54] [SPEAKER_03]: to take a look at cabinet papers and see what actually happened because that stimulus policy

[00:13:59] [SPEAKER_03]: included doubling and trebling the amount of money that the government gave to the first

[00:14:04] [SPEAKER_03]: tone bars which of course I nicknamed the first time vendors grant because what it meant was you

[00:14:10] [SPEAKER_03]: give people who weren't able to buy home and deposit means they can buy home they they go and

[00:14:14] [SPEAKER_03]: borrow 10 times as much from the bank yeah of course and they pay to the pay to the vendor

[00:14:19] [SPEAKER_02]: and it just keeps on a popping up everywhere around the world that doesn't have anything

[00:14:23] [SPEAKER_02]: well have we learned nothing from this but they were these they were different times in

[00:14:26] [SPEAKER_02]: that with you know the government was stepping in there because there was a downturn not because

[00:14:29] [SPEAKER_02]: there was an inflation worry but the fact was you know we're heading to recession so that that's

[00:14:34] [SPEAKER_02]: very different to the central bank I mean the central bank would be dropping rates in circumstances

[00:14:38] [SPEAKER_02]: like that wouldn't they which is why we didn't have a company and after quite some time as well

[00:14:42] [SPEAKER_03]: that was still putting right suppers the recession was happening because according to their

[00:14:46] [SPEAKER_03]: opinion it wouldn't be a recession but yeah it's I mean this putting up in some rates in

[00:14:50] [SPEAKER_03]: response to the inflation we had a big after covid was as you know Isabella Weber and

[00:14:56] [SPEAKER_03]: Blay and Blay fixed show extremely well and quite a bit of detail that was you know trying

[00:15:02] [SPEAKER_03]: to reduce demand but rather trying to reduce inflation when the inflation was coming from

[00:15:08] [SPEAKER_03]: supply chain shocks fundamentally and also increases in markups so you know you wanted to

[00:15:14] [SPEAKER_03]: make Jeff Bezos unemployed not the people in his detachment what are they called those places

[00:15:20] [SPEAKER_02]: despite dispatchers yes yeah well yeah but you know and well all you need more people in

[00:15:24] [SPEAKER_02]: those dispatchers to get more goods out to try and fix that gap and dampen the price rise because

[00:15:30] [SPEAKER_03]: again that's the story with the exception of events like covid and when you complete this

[00:15:36] [SPEAKER_03]: drop in the incredibly complex production supply chains we have most of the most of the inflation

[00:15:43] [SPEAKER_03]: where you actually can reduce inflation by increasing capacity a lot we talked a lot about

[00:15:48] [SPEAKER_02]: monetary policy in this first half when we come back I just want to talk more generally about

[00:15:51] [SPEAKER_02]: the labor market and where it's going I mean there's obviously you know things like AI which could

[00:15:55] [SPEAKER_02]: challenge employment but we're also seeing you know more jobs than ever available so why is that

[00:16:00] [SPEAKER_02]: happening and you know also we had that great resignation is that all gone now curious things happening

[00:16:05] [SPEAKER_02]: in the labor market so we'll look at all of that when we come back on the deep banking economics podcast

[00:16:10] [SPEAKER_00]: it's me and Steve Keen back in a moment this is the deep banking economics podcast with

[00:16:15] [SPEAKER_02]: Steve Keen and Phil Dobby well looking at the labor market today on the deep banking economics

[00:16:24] [SPEAKER_02]: podcast you know we've looked at the approach of central banks around the world which is if you're

[00:16:29] [SPEAKER_02]: if you're employed and you're spending too much and inflation is rising we want you to lose your job

[00:16:34] [SPEAKER_02]: basically so that you're just a truth therefore you don't spend therefore prices come down

[00:16:39] [SPEAKER_02]: it's as simple as that hardly any pain felt in that process although Steve I mean it's not

[00:16:44] [SPEAKER_02]: really happened to that extent America is talking about a soft landing so really there's you know

[00:16:47] [SPEAKER_02]: any employment hasn't shut up a great deal has it so so you begin to wonder does that mean that

[00:16:54] [SPEAKER_02]: the their approach is not working the fed policy approach isn't working all the fact that

[00:16:58] [SPEAKER_02]: it is working without people losing their job is that just co-incidence I mean what what exactly

[00:17:03] [SPEAKER_03]: is going on well it's a huge part of its coincidence and one of my favourite ways of indicating

[00:17:07] [SPEAKER_03]: this is to look at what happened in Japan because if you take a look at inflation in Japan

[00:17:12] [SPEAKER_03]: inflation in the UK inflation in the USA inflation in Germany what you find is a spike in inflation

[00:17:18] [SPEAKER_03]: after COVID which then fall back down now it countries like the American particular but the UK

[00:17:24] [SPEAKER_03]: and Australia and so we'll say oh it's because we put up interest rates in that reduced the rate of

[00:17:29] [SPEAKER_03]: inflation China and Japan's interest rate did not change in fact I think was negative

[00:17:35] [SPEAKER_03]: for all the way through and finally they put the rate up to zero now they in Japan not only had the

[00:17:40] [SPEAKER_03]: same pattern of rising inflation followed by falling inflation they had the lower rise in

[00:17:45] [SPEAKER_03]: inflation than most of the rest of the world so the argument that it was interest rate change

[00:17:51] [SPEAKER_03]: that managed to bring the inflation rate down I just wrong because one of the world's major

[00:17:55] [SPEAKER_03]: economies had the same effective performance in terms of rising and then falling in

[00:18:00] [SPEAKER_03]: without changing as interest rate one on earth and now of course they're loving inflation

[00:18:04] [SPEAKER_02]: in Japan because they've had so little of it for so long the now there's an opportunity to

[00:18:09] [SPEAKER_02]: for companies to say well we can put up prices upwards they were castigated for doing that before

[00:18:14] [SPEAKER_02]: and so you had that stagnant economy now they've got a little glimmer of inflation companies

[00:18:19] [SPEAKER_02]: are saying well okay we can afford to pay people a bit more that means there's more money for

[00:18:22] [SPEAKER_02]: people to spend therefore there's more money to buy stuff we can move our margins up a little bit

[00:18:27] [SPEAKER_02]: which will not be able to do for years so that allows us to invest so there can be all of

[00:18:31] [SPEAKER_02]: a certain starts to kick off so inflation is actually helping Japan right now yeah and this is

[00:18:36] [SPEAKER_03]: the point we made of who I podcast away that a certain amount of inflation not when you get to

[00:18:41] [SPEAKER_03]: doing above 10% the lowest they have about 40% which is what I define at the point where hyper

[00:18:46] [SPEAKER_03]: inflation is occurring but if you have the of the order between two and five percent rate of

[00:18:50] [SPEAKER_03]: inflation that actually operates as incentive for people to spend the money they've got because

[00:18:55] [SPEAKER_03]: otherwise you're seeing it reducing value that's in a way a bit like an artificial version

[00:19:01] [SPEAKER_03]: of what Brazil what of which was money which actually was depreciated by a blind design and because

[00:19:07] [SPEAKER_03]: it's depreciated it's been like a hot potato you pass it on to somebody else you get a higher level

[00:19:12] [SPEAKER_03]: economic activity so it's the turnover of money as well as the quantity of money that matters

[00:19:17] [SPEAKER_03]: and even though near classical economists you know for the third it's taught themselves

[00:19:21] [SPEAKER_03]: managers by talking about the velocity of money they don't really pay any real attention to it

[00:19:27] [SPEAKER_02]: no well if they did they might be a bit worried about the fact that it's been getting slower and slower

[00:19:31] [SPEAKER_02]: and slower over the decade and the fact that you're bad there but here's what about the numbers

[00:19:36] [SPEAKER_02]: of jobs then because there's a peculiar thing since the pandemic that we've got this rise

[00:19:40] [SPEAKER_02]: in jobs available so typically in the US there's between one and one point two job openings

[00:19:48] [SPEAKER_02]: per unemployed person it's getting back to that now but it was double that at one stage

[00:19:55] [SPEAKER_02]: over the last year or so it looks like it's going to settle down higher than it was before

[00:20:02] [SPEAKER_02]: so why more jobs available I mean and there's certainly as you know we hear about labor market

[00:20:07] [SPEAKER_02]: shortages even though the same number of people are you know our available in fact you know we've

[00:20:11] [SPEAKER_02]: seen massive immigration in the United States and other countries as well so there's actually

[00:20:15] [SPEAKER_02]: more people chasing jobs and yet there's lots of job openings as well so I mean that that

[00:20:22] [SPEAKER_02]: sounds like a healthy sign doesn't it I mean it can obviously mean that you get wage inflation

[00:20:27] [SPEAKER_02]: if you know too many people competing but of course it depends from sector to sector and that's

[00:20:32] [SPEAKER_02]: often ignored it's always looked at to an aggregate but why that many more jobs available now

[00:20:37] [SPEAKER_02]: you would have thought in this day and age with automation etc the numbers of jobs would be sliding

[00:20:42] [SPEAKER_03]: well I'm actually wondering what extent COVID is having an impact there because you know with people

[00:20:48] [SPEAKER_03]: the silver tending it doesn't exist anymore and and and pretending it doesn't have much of an

[00:20:53] [SPEAKER_03]: impact in fact as a substantial proportion of the population that ends up being paralyzed and

[00:20:58] [SPEAKER_03]: various ways you know any it's similar to you know diseases that just reduce your personal

[00:21:03] [SPEAKER_03]: motivation you have brain fog etc etc they've been a large number of people who just dropped

[00:21:08] [SPEAKER_03]: out of the workforce and and we don't know it's it's not well recorded and we no longer get any

[00:21:15] [SPEAKER_03]: associated with COVID itself anymore but that may be one reason why they're involved they

[00:21:20] [SPEAKER_03]: can see them people because it's not that they're of the vacancies of risen it's the number

[00:21:24] [SPEAKER_03]: of people who are available for jobs has declined because some people find they simply cannot

[00:21:28] [SPEAKER_03]: hold a job down anymore so you know it is a weird time it's it isn't you know you're

[00:21:34] [SPEAKER_03]: I could make much more definitive comments about phenomenal like that back on the 80s or 90s

[00:21:39] [SPEAKER_02]: and I can make now yeah because it is a confusing picture yeah I wonder though whether one thing

[00:21:44] [SPEAKER_02]: you share with other economists oh dear is there anything terrified what is what is this I have

[00:21:50] [SPEAKER_02]: to just if you know if you're wanting to look at where the economy's going you know if you're trying

[00:21:55] [SPEAKER_02]: to look at you're leading indicators so employment or employment expectations aren't a bad one

[00:22:04] [SPEAKER_02]: are they so we get things like for example the the conference board they've got the employment

[00:22:08] [SPEAKER_02]: trends index they've got you know they ask people whether they think that they will be employing

[00:22:13] [SPEAKER_02]: more people over the next six months or or less and then they ask other people whether they

[00:22:18] [SPEAKER_02]: feel as though you know there's lots of jobs around they've got the jobs plentiful index which

[00:22:22] [SPEAKER_02]: is other on his way up all well it's very down all of that actually quite useful guide isn't it

[00:22:26] [SPEAKER_03]: for how an economy is doing the hiring intention sometimes that's not as far as what I mean

[00:22:34] [SPEAKER_03]: the point that the man does fall on officially the companies decide to resrange paper it's already

[00:22:37] [SPEAKER_03]: happened exactly so I mean but employment expectations is is a leading indicator in that sense yeah

[00:22:43] [SPEAKER_03]: so all the time I've got a few too many jobs on my back so I don't follow that one carefully

[00:22:48] [SPEAKER_03]: anymore if we'll be able to weren't expecting a collapse in the climate I might be taking a look

[00:22:52] [SPEAKER_02]: at the numbers what other than that yeah I wish you had nothing that question now where

[00:22:55] [SPEAKER_02]: me they but they're not really you know it's my day-to-day job really but they are they

[00:23:01] [SPEAKER_02]: are writing so there's they are picking up so there's more influence so both sides of the

[00:23:06] [SPEAKER_02]: equation both the companies are saying me want to hire more people and people certainly can

[00:23:09] [SPEAKER_02]: be just saying slowly but it's happening enough for the fed to be there saying well okay

[00:23:15] [SPEAKER_02]: we'll keep an eye on that looks good but obviously we don't want it to rise too fast because

[00:23:18] [SPEAKER_02]: that could create inflation again but we also don't want it to fall because that would mean

[00:23:23] [SPEAKER_02]: that we can have to drop our interest rates because we could be heading towards a recession

[00:23:26] [SPEAKER_02]: so I mean you know it's which watched in in both directions but it's it generally moving up at

[00:23:32] [SPEAKER_02]: the moment so that's got to be a positive sign that's for the United States you know Europe is

[00:23:35] [SPEAKER_03]: a complete different story of course yeah well I mean to hold a lot of them the monetary

[00:23:40] [SPEAKER_03]: reasons behind it can be the the fact that the government is still running substantial not as

[00:23:46] [SPEAKER_03]: not the scale of care if it's substantial spending exceeding taxation which is a good thing that's

[00:23:51] [SPEAKER_03]: creating feed money which isn't necessary for the private sector to have you know business

[00:23:55] [SPEAKER_03]: turnover out of out of private transactions and the the thing which I'm a bit concerned about

[00:24:02] [SPEAKER_03]: I would wonder which direction this is going in the higher rates that have been imposed upon

[00:24:07] [SPEAKER_03]: private borrowers though I banks using the increase in reserve rates as effectively

[00:24:12] [SPEAKER_03]: in my opinion at the cover for it those higher rates are going to be cutting back people's demand

[00:24:17] [SPEAKER_03]: does offer credit based purchases so you like to see less investment driven by credit and

[00:24:25] [SPEAKER_03]: endless house purchases and the following that means in terms of employment in construction and so on so

[00:24:31] [SPEAKER_02]: I worry about that is a long term trend and of course you know also I mean even with the

[00:24:37] [SPEAKER_02]: large number of people at the house got high mortgage they've got less money to spend on other stuff as well

[00:24:41] [SPEAKER_02]: yeah and they've got to cut back another thing but I'm just wondering whether employment

[00:24:45] [SPEAKER_02]: is actually the key indicator for economic health you know is it actually more useful in GDP because

[00:24:51] [SPEAKER_02]: you can have a growing GDP for example but have less people employed you can have more automation

[00:24:56] [SPEAKER_02]: which you know is fantastic for the for the country but it means the wealthy are getting wealthy

[00:25:01] [SPEAKER_02]: other poor or not and that's a bad combination so elixir we equal weight GDP and unemployment as

[00:25:09] [SPEAKER_03]: the two key indicators. If you look back to the policies that exist in the positive world war

[00:25:13] [SPEAKER_03]: two period that was the emphatic focus of government policy because they'd seen what happened

[00:25:19] [SPEAKER_03]: when you had massive unemployment which was the 1930s leading to the 1940s in the World War II

[00:25:25] [SPEAKER_03]: a huge amount of that was seen as being motivated by leading unemployment explode after the

[00:25:30] [SPEAKER_03]: 1930s when it hit 25% the population in American 30% in Germany high levels in the rest of the

[00:25:37] [SPEAKER_03]: world as well and to quite the Australian white paper unemployment which I know well of course being an Aussie

[00:25:43] [SPEAKER_03]: and reading a stuff when I was a young man the white the 1945 white paper unemployment in Australia

[00:25:50] [SPEAKER_03]: said that this is virtually a quote the and the if it's got some anybody who believes in we have

[00:25:57] [SPEAKER_03]: to have worked hem analogy my police excuse the next set of expressions it said the emphasis

[00:26:02] [SPEAKER_03]: of government policy has to be maintained such pressure on demand as the guarantee as shortage

[00:26:06] [SPEAKER_03]: of men rather than a shortage of jobs so that was the thing the the the the

[00:26:12] [SPEAKER_03]: debilitating impact of long-term unemployment was regard was given the experience of the great

[00:26:18] [SPEAKER_03]: depression in the world war two was so traumatizing that that became the policy focus but

[00:26:25] [SPEAKER_02]: the nia classical economists are a lot more jobs so we won't we can in a face and we won't

[00:26:30] [SPEAKER_02]: implement right to be really low because we want there to be more jobs than our people and that

[00:26:33] [SPEAKER_03]: has like this the standard way that economists think about that is they're all wages are

[00:26:37] [SPEAKER_03]: high profits low bad bad bad but what often happens in short paper is a better guided this than

[00:26:44] [SPEAKER_03]: virtually all other economists when you have high wages that is often an encouragement for technological

[00:26:49] [SPEAKER_03]: innovation for firms to sidestep the impact of the tight labor market and the high wages

[00:26:54] [SPEAKER_03]: they're paying so the very original invention that that said off the manufacturing side of the

[00:27:03] [SPEAKER_03]: and that was something which went from letting one person spin a wheel to weath you know

[00:27:08] [SPEAKER_03]: now to turn the wool into in terms of strands of the third clothing manufacturing one person to

[00:27:16] [SPEAKER_03]: six people the spinach any that was profitable in in Scotland because wages were so high the same

[00:27:22] [SPEAKER_03]: invention would have failed in France because the wages were lower and the the cost of the machine

[00:27:28] [SPEAKER_03]: and the servicing costs and so on we're greater than the wages that it displaced so what you

[00:27:34] [SPEAKER_03]: get out this part of the dynamic process which is totally underrated by conventional economists

[00:27:39] [SPEAKER_03]: they don't look at the dynamics there so you actually it's almost a year one high employment

[00:27:43] [SPEAKER_03]: you want wage increases which will inspire when it's part of the top of technological

[00:27:48] [SPEAKER_03]: innovations that displays part of that labor so you know causing a rise in unemployment in that

[00:27:58] [SPEAKER_03]: pressure you want so an economy which is performing with you know with with the low unemployment

[00:28:02] [SPEAKER_03]: it is more likely to be one way innovations occur as well and that's what gives you progress over time yeah

[00:28:08] [SPEAKER_02]: well again I worked in a any industry completely useless industry the radio industry

[00:28:12] [SPEAKER_02]: it says no bloody good to anybody at all except plays a few nice tunes for them by and large

[00:28:16] [SPEAKER_02]: but I mean that's all been you know organ by computers these days so whereas a radio station in the

[00:28:20] [SPEAKER_02]: olden days when I started I don't know you might have 12 or 20 people who'd be presenting on

[00:28:26] [SPEAKER_02]: a day during the week doing a couple of hours each because you know that's all you could do by

[00:28:30] [SPEAKER_02]: time you'd land records back filled in commercial logs you know done all that taken phone calls

[00:28:36] [SPEAKER_02]: from listeners you know you exhausted by the end of that now it's all done by computer people

[00:28:40] [SPEAKER_02]: do for our shifts and they might do for our shifts simultaneously for a few different radio

[00:28:45] [SPEAKER_02]: stations because they're just voicing links rather than listening through the whole show it's

[00:28:48] [SPEAKER_02]: also you know the very very few people needed that industry now therefore they can't demand

[00:28:53] [SPEAKER_02]: particularly eye wages because you know there's many people who can do it you know you don't

[00:28:58] [SPEAKER_03]: or you have innovation but leader putting on planet and other other industries and that's been

[00:29:02] [SPEAKER_02]: though yeah I know then these people who don't podcast where cause people are making a fortune

[00:29:06] [SPEAKER_02]: but the we are absolutely we're rolling it yeah absolutely you shouldn't tell people

[00:29:11] [SPEAKER_02]: but it is interesting exactly trying to figure out whether what would happen in the end where I am

[00:29:16] [SPEAKER_02]: in sorry there's since the pandemic particularly over the last year our town is flooded with

[00:29:21] [SPEAKER_02]: cafes loads of them you think how are they all going to survive and also you know there's only

[00:29:27] [SPEAKER_02]: so many people to work in these cafes so you'd be thinking you know economic theory it suggests well

[00:29:32] [SPEAKER_02]: there's lots of those jobs available there's very few people those people are going to go and say

[00:29:36] [SPEAKER_02]: well I want 20 pounds per hour and the shopkeeper is going to be saying they're saying well okay

[00:29:41] [SPEAKER_02]: if we want to get you to stop you working at the shop next door that's what we're going to have to pay

[00:29:44] [SPEAKER_02]: but the reality is they can't afford 20 pounds per hour the shop would go bankrupt if they did that

[00:29:49] [SPEAKER_02]: so they you know so there's wages can only be pushed up so far before you know commercial reality

[00:29:54] [SPEAKER_03]: it's a bit of a bit of a bit of a dynamic process so they're forcing up and then feed to

[00:29:58] [SPEAKER_03]: whether you know the cost-free means reduced in other areas and profit-benegeny related by

[00:30:03] [SPEAKER_03]: new technological processes reduce your need for labor and you need for other input so

[00:30:10] [SPEAKER_03]: this is the dynamics of capitalism fasten that in the statics and not only boring they're

[00:30:16] [SPEAKER_03]: relevant as well and unfortunately our central bank managers think in terms of statics but that

[00:30:20] [SPEAKER_03]: even realizing are doing any more because they put the word dynamic before this the costy general

[00:30:25] [SPEAKER_03]: liquid-evolving models so you know it's it's this what do you get out of any living system

[00:30:32] [SPEAKER_03]: and you can regard the economies in extension of the living system of humanity is it is going to

[00:30:36] [SPEAKER_03]: have cycles and you're questioning if you've ever understand the cycles first before you can

[00:30:40] [SPEAKER_03]: talk about how you might be able to dampen them in some areas or raise them to a higher low

[00:30:46] [SPEAKER_03]: level if you're trying to change the actual level rather than the cycle of characteristics

[00:30:51] [SPEAKER_02]: none of this turns up a management economic and mainly economics does tend to say central banks

[00:30:56] [SPEAKER_02]: in particular basically they are pretty much saying its wages that drive inflation on thing

[00:30:59] [SPEAKER_03]: almost without exception well I mean they're doing they're calling inflationary expectations

[00:31:03] [SPEAKER_03]: and this is the funny thing and you mentioned employment expectations went back earlier in the

[00:31:10] [SPEAKER_03]: nonsense that came out of mainstream economics is that inflation has set by expectations

[00:31:15] [SPEAKER_03]: of inflation this came out of Milton Fraser paper the optimal quantity of money written back

[00:31:19] [SPEAKER_03]: in the 1950s and here that's where the idea of helicopter money came from as well you literally

[00:31:24] [SPEAKER_03]: had the analogy imagine a helicopter flies over this country and drops $1,000 one dollar bills

[00:31:30] [SPEAKER_03]: we're previous there were only one thousand there were now two thousand what's going to happen

[00:31:35] [SPEAKER_03]: and that argument about people then it started to expect the helicopter to turn up

[00:31:41] [SPEAKER_03]: and therefore because they expect the helicopter to turn up they're putting up their process

[00:31:45] [SPEAKER_03]: even though markets roll in in completely equilibrium that's just a childish vision of how money

[00:31:52] [SPEAKER_03]: has created a childish vision of a capitalist economy but that's where the idea of the inflationary

[00:31:57] [SPEAKER_03]: expectations cause inflation so Milton Fraser solved the idea that if you can reduce

[00:32:02] [SPEAKER_03]: expectations of inflation you can bring the rate of inflation down without actually

[00:32:07] [SPEAKER_03]: affecting the level of unemployment well what we do that's that's the nonsense that gave us

[00:32:12] [SPEAKER_02]: the block for the set so if a central bank pushes up interest rates wouldn't the theory be

[00:32:18] [SPEAKER_02]: that people have got less money therefore companies are going to feel the squeeze as well

[00:32:24] [SPEAKER_02]: and company profits would fall wouldn't that be the argument and the partiality is the argument

[00:32:28] [SPEAKER_03]: what they were ignoring is when you're putting up rates on government bonds there's an impact

[00:32:33] [SPEAKER_03]: upon the value the face value of those bonds and this is what we're at silicon bank

[00:32:37] [SPEAKER_03]: silicon valley bank unstuck but if you're doing that the new bonds ratio are actually paying

[00:32:43] [SPEAKER_03]: more money from the government government created money to the private sector that buys

[00:32:47] [SPEAKER_03]: these bonds so there's a extent to which putting up rates on government bonds actually

[00:32:53] [SPEAKER_03]: is a simulated economy specifically in the financial sector but that's something which is left out

[00:32:59] [SPEAKER_03]: of mainstream thinking that simply treat this as being the high rate of rate of interest

[00:33:03] [SPEAKER_03]: leads to it corporations looking at pre-searcher cash flow flows discounting them by a

[00:33:11] [SPEAKER_03]: higher interest rate therefore you get a low-end net present value therefore low-end

[00:33:14] [SPEAKER_03]: this less and therefore you slow down the level of economic activity that reduces demand

[00:33:20] [SPEAKER_03]: for workers that reduces wage rises and that reduces inflationary expectations not inflation

[00:33:27] [SPEAKER_03]: itself of course expectations for inflation or for etc etc I'm sorry I can't see where I put my

[00:33:33] [SPEAKER_02]: volume.

[00:33:34] [SPEAKER_02]: Well here because we know my mum went to go shopping and they say it's going to cost you

[00:33:38] [SPEAKER_02]: 10% more she always goes well I wasn't expecting that so that's not him yet and so they say

[00:33:43] [SPEAKER_02]: okay well if you want to expect and you will only charge a 5% more than but let me so they live

[00:33:47] [SPEAKER_02]: the fair to see land on their real world.

[00:33:49] [SPEAKER_02]: Now let me give you some numbers then just before we finish off here

[00:33:52] [SPEAKER_02]: yeah I couldn't use because I want to get fact I know it's a road to some of you're trying

[00:33:56] [SPEAKER_02]: out on the podcast so you must be happy if we look at from 2019 the beginning of 2019 the

[00:34:02] [SPEAKER_02]: first quarter of the 32 to 2024 so before the pandemic through to the beginning of this year

[00:34:08] [SPEAKER_02]: over that period actually sorry from January they have got let me get the strike from

[00:34:13] [SPEAKER_02]: January we're going to use numbers we've got to get it right from January 2020 to January

[00:34:17] [SPEAKER_02]: 2024 the first quarter of 2024 anyway for the UK if the aggregate inflation so prices over that

[00:34:24] [SPEAKER_02]: four year period went up 21% that's where we've come out the other side from wages went up 23

[00:34:30] [SPEAKER_02]: percent so actually beat inflation ever so slightly corporate profits have I guess 200 percent

[00:34:37] [SPEAKER_02]: not quite that bad 53% though so still you know more than twice the rate of inflation

[00:34:42] [SPEAKER_03]: and that comes as well as but with us points that is actually increasing on mark

[00:34:46] [SPEAKER_03]: up the road most the inflation not increasing on wages yeah unless included in that

[00:34:50] [SPEAKER_02]: corporate profits is the final sector with the impact of the higher you know as you've just been

[00:34:55] [SPEAKER_02]: disbanded earlier yeah which could be part of it as well so for the US although you know

[00:35:00] [SPEAKER_02]: you would have thought they'd be the difference would be greater in the US if that was the case

[00:35:03] [SPEAKER_02]: but in fact slightly less so for the US inflation 21% wages 23% face similar to the UK in fact

[00:35:12] [SPEAKER_02]: less though 39% growth in corporate profits for Australia 14.4% inflation wages 12.5%

[00:35:20] [SPEAKER_02]: corporate profits 44% so it's the same everywhere Germany though inflation 14 and a half percent

[00:35:27] [SPEAKER_02]: wages just 6.4% corporate profits 14% so Germany because they are struggling as an economy

[00:35:33] [SPEAKER_02]: because they're an export nation and just not being able to float as much stuff to China

[00:35:37] [SPEAKER_02]: they really are suffering and corporate profits are down because they're export earnings and

[00:35:43] [SPEAKER_02]: not being able to you know abuse the privileged too much with the Chinese because they really don't have

[00:35:48] [SPEAKER_03]: any money yeah well this is the I mean Germany is pretty much given up at high export

[00:35:52] [SPEAKER_03]: focus the whole the master treaty i think is finally starting to cripple that economy

[00:35:57] [SPEAKER_03]: whereas the China is still you know happily creating money because they know that's what a government

[00:36:02] [SPEAKER_03]: should do and financing infrastructure projects and also causing a huge amount of cash that

[00:36:08] [SPEAKER_03]: circulates in the economy and drives the private sector so you know we've got examples out there

[00:36:12] [SPEAKER_03]: if we're not swallowing near a classical cool aid at least a bit around comes but we're never

[00:36:17] [SPEAKER_03]: going to look at them because hey we like the near a classical cool aid yeah and you can't say

[00:36:22] [SPEAKER_02]: in Germany that wages are driving inflation inflation is at 14.5% wages are growing by 6%

[00:36:27] [SPEAKER_03]: yeah really and that's probably part of what's leading to the the the rosin racism in

[00:36:31] [SPEAKER_03]: Germany but most of Europe because they're blaming migrants for it when in fact it's bad

[00:36:36] [SPEAKER_03]: economic policy but these numbers tell a lot don't they? I don't know why they're not used more

[00:36:41] [SPEAKER_02]: often just look at inflation look at wage growth and look at corporate profits and the end then go

[00:36:45] [SPEAKER_02]: we're hang on a second one of those is really add to kielter has that happening yep good numbers to

[00:36:50] [SPEAKER_02]: end on I like it yeah yeah very good okay catch an exam Steve I can act by the deep on King economics podcast

[00:37:05] [SPEAKER_04]: Can you know that you can get a quick analysis of the phones trip through a cafe

[00:37:10] [SPEAKER_04]: and say a fluke not a panic health risk average day with their creative

[00:37:16] [SPEAKER_04]: form of sites themselves the hard-narchic flanks for tiefen rainwater

[00:37:21] [SPEAKER_04]: an easy disk in the trombo verpin and the rest is that's going to do your washing machine

[00:37:25] [SPEAKER_04]: because you always have your best there are now the best disks of peace we'll go back to

[00:37:31] [SPEAKER_04]: on Kinden of the van.